Paul Krugman
Professor, Princeton University
My
formal charge in this essay is to talk about my "life philosophy". Let
me make it clear at the outset that I
have
no intention of following instructions, since I don't know anything special
about life in general. I believe it
was
Schumpeter who claimed to be not only the best economist, but also the
best horseman and the best lover in
his
native Austria. I don't ride horses, and have few illusions on other scores.
(I am, however, a pretty good
cook).
What
I want to talk about in this essay is something more restricted: some thoughts
about thinking, and
particularly
how to go about doing interesting economics. I think that among economists
of my generation I can
claim
to have a fairly distinctive intellectual style -- not necessarily a better
style than my colleagues, for there
are
many ways to be a good economist, but one that has served me well. The
essence of that style is a general
research
strategy that can be summarized in a few rules; I also view my more policy-oriented
writing and
speaking
as ultimately grounded in the same principles. I'll get to my rules for
research later in this essay. I
think
I can best introduce those rules, however, by describing how (it seems
to me) I stumbled into the way I
work.
ORIGINS
Most
young economists today enter the field from the technical end. Originally
intending a career in hard science
or
engineering, they slip down the scale into the most rigorous of the social
sciences. The advantages of entering
economics
from that direction are obvious: one arrives already well trained in mathematics,
one finds the concept
of
formal modeling natural. It is not, however, where I come from. My first
love was history; I studied little
math,
picking up what I needed as I went along.
Nonetheless,
I got deeply involved in economics early, working as a research assistant
(on world energy markets)
to
William Nordhaus while still only a junior at Yale. Graduate school followed
naturally, and I wrote my first
really
successful paper -- a theoretical analysis of balance of payments crises
-- while still at MIT. I discovered
that
I was facile with small mathematical models, with a knack for finding simplifying
assumptions that made
them
tractable. Still, when I left graduate school I was, in my own mind at
least, somewhat directionless. I was
not
sure what to work on; I was not even sure whether I really liked research.
I found
my intellectual feet quite suddenly, in January 1978. Feeling somewhat
lost, I paid a visit to my old
advisor
Rudi Dornbusch. I described several ideas to him, including a vague notion
that the monopolistic
competition
models I had studied in a short course offered by Bob Solow -- especially
the lovely little model of
Dixit
and Stiglitz -- might have something to do with international trade. Rudi
flagged that idea as potentially
very
interesting indeed; I went home to work on it seriously; and within a few
days I realized that I had hold of
something
that would form the core of my professional life.
What
had I found? The point of my trade models was not particularly startling
once one thought about it:
economies
of scale could be an independent cause of international trade, even in
the absence of comparative
advantage.
This was a new insight to me, but had (as I soon discovered) been pointed
out many times before by
critics
of conventional trade theory. The models I worked out left some loose ends
hanging; in particular, they
typically
had many equilibria. Even so, to make the models tractable I had to make
obviously unrealistic
assumptions.
And once I had made those assumptions, the models were trivially simple;
writing them up left me
no
opportunity to display any high-powered technique. So one might have concluded
that I was doing nothing very
interesting
(and that was what some of my colleagues were to tell me over the next
few years). Yet what I saw --
and
for some reason saw almost immediately -- was that all of these features
were virtues, not vices, that they
added
up to a program that could lead to years of productive research.
I was,
of course, only saying something that critics of conventional theory had
been saying for decades. Yet my
point
was not part of the mainstream of international economics. Why? Because
it had never been expressed in
nice
models. The new monopolistic competition models gave me a tool to open
cleanly what had previously been
regarded
as a can of worms. More important, however, I suddenly realized the remarkable
extent to which the
methodology
of economics creates blind spots. We just don't see what we can't formalize.
And the biggest blind
spot
of all has involved increasing returns. So there, right at hand, was my
mission: to look at things from a
slightly
different angle, and in so doing to reveal the obvious, things that had
been right under our noses all the
time.
The
models I wrote down that winter and spring were incomplete, if one demanded
of them that they specify
exactly
who produced what. And yet they told meaningful stories. It took me a long
time to express clearly what I
was
doing, but eventually I realized that one way to deal with a difficult
problem is to change the question -- in
particular
by shifting levels. A detailed analysis may be extremely nasty, yet an
aggregative or systemic
description
that is far easier may tell you all you need to know.
To
get this system or aggregate level description required, of course, accepting
the basically silly assumptions of
symmetry
that underlay the Dixit-Stiglitz and related models. Yet these silly assumptions
seemed to let me tell
stories
that were persuasive, and that could not be told using the hallowed assumptions
of the standard
competitive
model. What I began to realize was that in economics we are always making
silly assumptions; it's
just
that some of them have been made so often that they come to seem natural.
And so one should not reject a
model
as silly until one sees where its assumptions lead.
Finally,
the simplicity of the models may have frustrated my lingering urge to show
off the technical skills I had
so
laboriously acquired in graduate school, but was, I soon realized, central
to the enterprise. Trade theorists had
failed
to address the role of increasing returns, not out of empirical conviction,
but because they thought it was
too
hard to model. How much more effective, then, to show that it could be
almost childishly simple?
And
so, before my 25th birthday, I basically knew what I was going to do with
my professional life. I don't know
what
would have happened if my grand project had met with rejection from other
economists -- perhaps I would
have
turned cranky, perhaps I would have lost faith and abandoned the effort.
But in fact all went astonishingly
well.
In my own mind, the curve of my core research since that January of 1978
has followed a remarkably
consistent
path. Within a few months, I had written up a basic monopolistic competition
trade model -- as it
turned
out, simultaneously and independently with similar models by Avinash Dixit
and Victor Norman, on one
side,
and Kelvin Lancaster, on the other. I had some trouble getting that paper
published -- receiving the
dismissive
rejection by a flagship journal (the QJE) that seems to be the fate of
every innovation in economics --
but
pressed on. From 1978 to roughly the end of 1984 I focussed virtually all
my research energies on the role of
increasing
returns and imperfect competition in international trade. (I took one year
off to work in the US
government;
but more about that below). What had been a personal quest turned into
a movement, as others
followed
the same path. Above all, Elhanan Helpman -- a deep thinker whose integrity
and self-discipline were
useful
counterparts to my own flakiness and disorganization -- first made crucial
contibutions himself, then
talked
me into collaborative work. Our magnum opus, Market Structure and Foreign
Trade, served the purpose of
making
our ideas not only respectable but almost standard: iconoclasm to orthodoxy
in seven years.
For
whatever reason, I allowed my grand project on increasing returns to lie
fallow for a few years in the 1980s,
and
turned my attention to international finance. My work in this area consisted
primarily of small models
inspired
by current policy issues; although these models lacked the integrating
theme of my trade models, I think
that
my finance work is to some extent unified by its intellectual style, which
is very similar to that of my work
on
trade.
In
1990 I returned to the economics of increasing returns from a new direction.
I suddenly realized that the
techniques
that had allowed us to legitimize the role of increasing returns in trade
could also be used to reclaim
a
whole outcast field: that of economic geography, the location of activity
in space. Here, perhaps even more than
in
trade, was a field full of empirical insights, good stories, and obvious
practical importance, lying neglected
right
under our noses because nobody had seen a good way to formalize it. For
me, it was like reliving the best
moments
of my intellectual childhood. Doing geography is hard work; it requires
a lot of hard thinking to make
the
models look trivial, and I am increasingly finding that I need the computer
as an aid not just to data analysis
but
even to theorizing. Yet it is immensely rewarding. For me, the biggest
thrill in theory is the moment when
your
model tells you something that should have been obvious all along, something
that you can immediately
relate
to what you know about the world, and yet which you didn't really appreciate.
Geography still has that
thrill.
My
work on geography seems, at the time of writing, to be leading me even
further afield. In particular, there are
obvious
affinities between the concepts that arise naturally in geographic models
and the language of traditional
development
economics -- the "high development theory" that flourished in the 1940s
and 50s, then collapsed. So I
expect
that my basic research project will continue to widen in scope.
RULES FOR RESEARCH
In
the course of describing my formative moment in 1978, I have already implicitly
given my four basic rules for
research.
Let me now state them explicitly, then explain. Here are the rules:
1. Listen to the Gentiles
2. Question the question
3. Dare to be silly
4. Simplify, simplify
Listen to the Gentiles
What
I mean by this rule is "Pay attention to what intelligent people are saying,
even if they do not have your
customs
or speak your analytical language." The point may perhaps best be explained
by example. When I began
my
rethinking of international trade, there was already a sizeable literature
criticizing conventional trade theory.
Empiricists
pointed out that trade took place largely between countries with seemingly
similar factor
endowments,
and that much of this trade involved intra-industry exchanges of seemingly
similar products. Acute
observers
pointed to the importance of economies of scale and imperfect competition
in actual international
markets.
Yet all of this intelligent commentary was ignored by mainstream trade
theorists -- after all, their
critics
often seemed to have an imperfect understanding of comparative advantage,
and had no coherent models of
their
own to offer; so why pay attention to them? The result was that the profession
overlooked evidence and
stories
that were right under its nose.
The
same story is repeated in geography. Geographers and regional scientists
have amassed a great deal of
evidence
on the nature and importance of localized external economies, and organized
that evidence intelligently
if
not rigorously. Yet economists have ignored what they had to say, because
it comes from people speaking the
wrong
language.
I do
not mean to say that formal economic analysis is worthless, and that anybody's
opinion on economic matters
is
as good as anyone else's. On the contrary! I am a strong believer in the
importance of models, which are to our
minds
what spear-throwers were to stone age arms: they greatly extend the power
and range of our insight. In
particular,
I have no sympathy for those people who criticize the unrealistic simplifications
of model-builders,
and
imagine that they achieve greater sophistication by avoiding stating their
assumptions clearly. The point is to
realize
that economic models are metaphors, not truth. By all means express your
thoughts in models, as pretty as
possible
(more on that below). But always remember that you may have gotten the
metaphor wrong, and that
someone
else with a different metaphor may be seeing something that you are missing.
Question the question
There
was a limited literature on external economies and international trade
before 1978. It was never, however,
very
influential, because it seemed terminally messy; even the simplest models
became bogged down in a
taxonomy
of possible outcomes. What has since become clear is that this messiness
arose in large part because
the
modelers were asking their models to do what traditional trade models do,
which is to predict a precise
pattern
of specialization and trade. Yet why ask that particular question? Even
in the Heckscher-Ohlin model, the
point
you want to make is something like "A country tends to export goods whose
production is intensive in the
factors
in which that country is abundant"; if your specific model tells you that
capital-abundant country Home
exports
capital-intensive good X, this is valuable because it sharpens your understanding
of that insight, not
because
you really care about these particular details of a patently oversimplified
model.
It
turns out that if you don't ask for the kind of detail that you get in
the two-sector, two-good classical model, an
external
economy model needn't be at all messy. As long as you ask "system" questions
like how welfare and
world
income are distributed, it is possible to make very simple and neat models.
And it's really these system
questions
that we are interested in. The focus on excessive detail was, to put it
bluntly, a matter of carrying over
ingrained
prejudices from an overworked model into a domain where they only made
life harder.
The
same is true in a number of areas in which I have worked. In general, if
people in a field have bogged down
on
questions that seem very hard, it is a good idea to ask whether they are
really working on the right questions.
Often
some other question is not only easier to answer but actually more interesting!
(One drawback of this trick
is
that it often gets people angry. An academic who has spent years on a hard
problem is rarely grateful when you
suggest
that his field can be revived by bypassing it).
Dare to be silly
If
you want to publish a paper in economic theory, there is a safe approach:
make a conceptually minor but
mathematically
difficult extension to some familiar model. Because the basic assumptions
of the model are
already
familiar, people will not regard them as strange; because you have done
something technically difficult,
you
will be respected for your demonstration of firepower. Unfortunately, you
will not have added much to human
knowledge.
What
I found myself doing in the new trade theory was pretty much the opposite.
I found myself using
assumptions
that were unfamiliar, and doing very simple things with them. Doing this
requires a lot of
self-confidence,
because initially people (especially referees) are almost certain not simply
to criticize your
work
but to ridicule it. After all, your assumptions will surely look peculiar:
a continuum of goods all with
identical
production functions, entering symmetrically into utility? Countries of
identical economic size, with
mirror-image
factor endowments? Why, people will ask, should they be interested in a
model with such silly
assumptions
-- especially when there are evidently much smarter young people who demonstrate
their quality by
solving
hard problems?
What
seems terribly hard for many economists to accept is that all our models
involve silly assumptions. Given
what
we know about cognitive psychology, utility maximization is a ludicrous
concept; equilibrium pretty foolish
outside
of financial markets; perfect competition a howler for most industries.
The reason for making these
assumptions
is not that they are reasonable but that they seem to help us produce models
that are helpful
metaphors
for things that we think happen in the real world.
Consider
the example which some economists seem to think is not simply a useful
model but revealed divine
truth:
the Arrow-Debreu model of perfect competition with utility maximization
and complete markets. This is
indeed
a wonderful model -- not because its assumptions are remotely plausible
but because it helps us think
more
clearly about both the nature of economic efficiency and the prospects
for achieving efficiency under a
market
system. It is actually a piece of inspired, marvellous silliness.
What
I believe is that the age of creative silliness is not past. Virtue, as
an economic theorist, does not consist in
squeezing
the last drop of blood out of assumptions that have come to seem natural
because they have been used
in
a few hundred earlier papers. If a new set of assumptions seems to yield
a valuable set of insights, then never
mind
if they seem strange.
Simplify, simplify
The
injunction to dare to be silly is not a license to be undisciplined. In
fact, doing really innovative theory
requires
much more intellectual discipline than working in a well-established literature.
What is really hard is to
stay
on course: since the terrain is unfamilar, it is all too easy to find yourself
going around in circles.
Somewhere
or other Keynes wrote that "it is astonishing what foolish things a man
thinking alone can come
temporarily
to believe". And it is also crucial to express your ideas in a way that
other people, who have not
spent
the last few years wrestling with your problems and are not eager to spend
the next few years wrestling
with
your answers, can understand without too much effort.
Fortunately,
there is a strategy that does double duty: it both helps you keep control
of your own insights, and
makes
those insights accessible to others. The strategy is: always try to express
your ideas in the simplest
possible
model. The act of stripping down to this minimalist model will force you
to get to the essence of what
you
are trying to say (and will also make obvious to you those situations in
which you actually have nothing to
say).
And this minimalist model will then be easy to explain to other economists
as well.
I have
used the "minimum necessary model" approach over and over again: using
a one-factor, one-industry model
to
explain the basic role of monopolistic competition in trade; assuming sector-specific
labor rather than full
Heckscher-Ohlin
factor substitution to explain the effects of intraindustry trade; working
with symmetric
countries
to assess the role of reciprocal dumping; and so on. In each case the effect
has been to allow me to
tackle
a subject widely viewed as formidably difficult with what appears, at first
sight, to be ridiculous
simplicity.
The
downside of this strategy is, of course, that many of your colleagues will
tend to assume that an insight that
can
be expressed in a cute little model must be trivial and obvious -- it takes
some sophistication to realize that
simplicity
may be the result of years of hard thinking. I have heard the story that
when Joseph Stiglitz was being
considered
for tenure at Yale, one of his senior colleagues belittled his work, saying
that it consisted mostly of
little
models rather than deep theorems. Another colleague then asked, "But couldn't
you say the same about Paul
Samuelson"?
"Yes, I could", replied Joe's opponent. I have heard the same reaction
to my own work. Luckily,
there
are enough sophisticated economists around that in the end intellectual
justice is usually served. And there
is
a special delight in managing not only to boldly go where no economist
has gone before, but to do so in a way
that
seems after the fact to be almost childs' play.
I have
now described my basic rules for research. I have illustrated them with
my experience in developing the
"new
trade theory" and with my more recent extension of that work to economic
geography, because these are the
core
of my work. But I have also done quite a lot of other stuff, which (it
seems to me) is also in some sense part
of
the same enterprise. So in the remainder of this essay I want to talk about
this other work, and in particular
about
how the policy economist and the analytical economist can coexist in the
same person.
POLICY-RELEVANT WORK
Most
economic theorists keep their hands off current policy issues -- or if
they do get involved in policy debates,
do
so only after the midpoint of their career, as something that follows creative
theorizing rather than coexists
with
it. There seems to be a consensus that the clarity and singleness of purpose
required to do good theory are
incompatible
with the tolerance for messy issues required to be active in policy discussion.
For me, however, it
has
never worked that way. I have interspersed my academic career with a number
of consulting ventures for
various
governments and public agencies, as well as a full year in the US government.
I have also written a book,
The
Age of Diminished Expectations, aimed at a non-technical audience. And
I have written a pretty steady
stream
of papers that are motivated not by the inner logic of my research but
by the attempt to make sense of
some
currently topical policy debate -- e.g., Third World debt relief, target
zones for exchange rates, the rise of
regional
trading blocs. All of this hasn't seemed to hurt my research, and indeed
some of my favorite papers have
grown
out of this policy-oriented work.
Why
doesn't policy-relevant work seem to conflict with my "real" research?
I think that it's because I have been
able
to approach policy issues using almost exactly the same method that I use
in my more basic work. Paying
attention
to newspaper reports or the concerns of central bankers and finance ministers
is just another form of
listening
to the Gentiles. Trying to find a useful way of defining their problems
is pretty much the same as
questioning
the question in theory. Confronting supposedly knowledgeable people with
an unorthodox view of an
issue
certainly requires the courage to be silly. And of course, ruthless simplification
is worth even more in
policy
discussion than in theory for its own sake.
So
doing policy-relevant economics does not, for me, mean a drastic change
in intellectual style. And it has its
own
payoffs. Let's be honest and admit that these include invitations to fancier
conferences and speaking
engagements
at much higher fees than an academic purist is likely to get. Let's also
admit that one of the joys of
policy
research is the opportunity to shock the bourgeoisie, to point out the
hollowness or silliness of official
positions.
For example, I know that I was not the only international economist to
have some fun pointing out the
absurdities
of the Maastricht Treaty, and was not above some wicked pleasure when the
ERM crisis I and others
had
long predicted actually came to pass in the fall of 1992. The main payoff
to policy work, though, is
intellectual
stimulation. Not all real-world questions are interesting -- I find that
almost anything having to do
with
taxation is better than a sleeping pill -- but every couple of years, if
not more often, the international
economy
throws up a question that gives rise to exciting research. I have been
stimulated to write theory papers
by
the Plaza and the Louvre, by the Brady Plan, NAFTA, and EMU. All of them
are papers that I think could stand
on
their own, even without the policy context.
There
is, of course, always a risk that an economist who gets onto the policy
circuit will no longer have enough
time
for real research. I certainly write an awfully large number of conference
papers; I am a very fast writer,
but
perhaps it is a gift I overuse. Still, I think that the big danger of doing
policy research is not so much the
drain
on your time as the threat to your values. It is easy to be seduced into
the belief that direct influence on
policy
is more important than just writing papers -- I've seen it happen to many
colleagues. Once you start down
that
road, once you begin to think that David Mulford matters more than Bob
Solow, or to prefer hobnobbing with
the
Ruritanian finance minister to talking theory with Avinash Dixit, you are
probably lost to research. Pretty
soon
you'll probably start using "impact" as a verb.
Fortunately,
while I love playing around with policy issues, I have never been able
to take policy makers very
seriously.
This lack of seriousness gets me into occasional trouble -- like the time
that a gentle parenthetical
joke
about the French in a conference paper led to an extended diatribe from
the French official attending the
conference
-- and may exclude me from ever holding any important policy position.
But that's OK: in the end, I
would
rather write a few more good papers than hold a position of real power.
(Note to the policy world: this
doesn't
mean that I would necessarily turn down such a position if it were offered!)
REGRETS
There
are a lot of things about my life and personality that I regret -- if things
have gone astonishingly well for
me
professionally, they have been by no means as easy or happy elsewhere.
But in this essay I only want to talk
about
professional regrets.
A minor
regret is that I have never engaged in really serious empirical work. It's
not that I dislike facts or real
numbers.
Indeed, I find light empirical work in the form of tables, charts, and
perhaps a few regressions quite
congenial.
But the serious business of building and thoroughly analyzing a data set
is something I never seem to
get
around to. I think that this is partly because many of my ideas do not
easily lend themselves to standard
econometric
testing. Mostly, though, it is because I lack the patience and organizational
ability. Every year I
promise
to try to do some real empirical work. Next year I really will!
A more
important regret is that while the MIT course evaluations rate me as a
pretty good lecturer, I have not yet
succeeded
in generating a string of really fine students, the kind who reflect glory
on their teacher. I can make
excuses
for this failing -- students often prefer advisers who are more methodical
and less intuitive, and I all too
often
scare students off by demanding that they use less math and more economics.
It's also true that I probably
seem
busy and distracted, and perhaps I am just not imposing enough in person
to be inspiring (if I were only a
few
inches taller ...). Whatever the reasons, I wish I could do better, and
intend to try.
All
in all, though, I've been very lucky. A lot of that luck has to do with
the accidents that led me to stumble onto
an
intellectual style that has served me extremely well. I've tried, in this
essay, to define and explain that style.
Is
this a life philosophy? Of course not. I'm not even sure that it is an
economic research philosophy, since what
works
for one economist may not work for another. But it's how I do research,
and it works for me.
==========================================================================
INCIDENTS FROM MY CAREER
My
personal life is not interesting. I don't mean that I am an especially
deadly dinner companion, or that I have
not
had my fair share of life's joys and miseries. What I mean is that only
my friends and family are interested in
the
more intimate details of my history; nobody reading this essay wants to
know about my marital or health
problems
(or if you do, it's none of your business!). What readers want to know,
presumably, is how I came to be
the
particular sort of economist I am -- how I came to write the books and
papers I did, and more generally how I
arrived
both at the particular ideas I have inflicted on the world and at whatever
distinctive features there are in
my
intellectual style. Lives are seamless, so everything affects everything
else: my economic theories have no
doubt
been influenced by my relationship with my cats (which is, I hasten to
add, mature and mutually supportive)
and
vice versa. What I will try to focus on in this essay, however, are the
incidents in my professional life that I
think
were important -- the experiences that in obvious ways influenced the way
I write and think.
I will
also, along the way, try to convey something of the flavor of what it is
to be a successful academic
economist
in late 20th-century America. No matter what we may say, none of us is
a philosopher-saint, and you
can't
fully understand the development of economic ideas without a sense of the
structure of rewards that
economists
face. That's why I call this essay "Incidents from my career"; I may have
been in pursuit of Truth and
Beauty,
but I, like everyone, was also in pursuit of success.
Most
of this essay is a series of vignettes from my professional life, in chronological
order. I follow this story of
my
life with a discussion of what I think was the point of it all: my personal
assessment of what I did to and for
economics.
1. Becoming an economist
I have
a self-serving theory: interesting ideas have very little to do with interesting
life experiences. According
to
this theory a person who has grown up in eight countries and speaks five
languages, who has taken a dogsled
across
Siberia and a raft down the Amazon, is no more likely to have a deep insight
into social science than
someone
who grew up in a safe middle-class suburb reading science-fiction novels.
I hope
this theory is true, because I have an utterly conventional background.
I was born in 1953, at the peak of
the
baby boom. I grew up in the New York suburbs, had an ordinary education
(I attended one of the many John F.
Kennedy
High Schools), and went on to four uneventful college years.
Admittedly,
there were those science fiction novels. Indeed, they may have been what
made me go into
economics.
Those who read the stuff may be aware of the classic Foundation trilogy
by Isaac Asimov. It is one of
the
few science fiction series that deals with social scientists -- the "psychohistorians",
who use their
understanding
of the mathematics of society to save civilization as the Galactic Empire
collapses. I loved
Foundation,
and in my early teens my secret fantasy was to become a psychohistorian.
Unfortunately, there's no
such
thing (yet). I was and am fascinated by history, but the craft of history
is far better at the what and the
when
than the why, and I eventually wanted more. As for social sciences other
than economics, I am interested in
their
subjects but cannot get excited about their methods -- the power of economic
models to show how plausible
assumptions
yield surprising conclusions, to distill clear insights from seemingly
murky issues, has no counterpart
yet
in political science or sociology. Someday there will exist a unified social
science of the kind that Asimov
imagined,
but for the time being economics is as close to psychohistory as you can
get.
And
so in college I became an economics major. I didn't take all that many
economics courses; in fact, I took
only
slightly more than the minimum required by the major, filling up the extra
time with a lot of history courses.
But
I was very lucky to receive an early apprenticeship in doing real economic
research. In the spring of 1973
(my
junior year) William Nordhaus and Tjalling Koopmans offered an undergraduate
seminar on energy and
natural
resource issues. In my effort to find a topic for a term paper I happened
to stumble across international
cross-section
data on the price and consumption of gasoline, and used that data to write
a paper suggesting that
long-run
demand for gasoline is in fact fairly price-elastic -- contrary to the
prevailing belief in the US at that
time.
On the strength of that paper Nordhaus asked me to work for him as a research
assistant; and it was at that
point
that I can say that I effectively became a professional economist.
Bill
Nordhaus was and is a fine economist in the classic MIT, which is to say
Robert Solow, tradition. There are
several
different ways of doing good economics. You can try to prove deep theorems;
and who would deny the
importance
of the work of, say, the young Kenneth Arrow? Or you can do detailed, nitty-gritty
empirical work;
and
I deeply admire the work of, say, a Zvi Griliches. But what has always
appealed to me, ever since I saw
Nordhaus
practice it on energy, is the MIT style: small models applied to real problems,
blending real-world
observation
and a little mathematics to cut through to the core of an issue.
The
first summer I worked for him, Nordhaus began with only a vague sense of
how to think about the problem of
appropriate
pricing of energy. I was able to watch the process by which he crystallized
that vague sense into a
model,
and then was able to see the way in which that model transformed everyone's
perception of the issue. It
would
be several years before I was ready to try the same thing, but I was lucky
to get so early a view of what
doing
economics is really about. I graduated from Yale in 1974. As Nordhaus's
protege, it was only natural that I
go
on to graduate school at MIT.
The
mid-1970s at MIT were a heady time. For one thing, those were the days
of the rational expectations
revolution
in macroeconomics. MIT's senior faculty were a bit skeptical, and Keynesian
ideas continued to be
taught
-- a fortunate thing, because by the 1980s equilibrium macro would become
a faith held in the teeth of
adverse
evidence. Nonetheless, for students it was a time when everything seemed
up for reinvention. Saddle-path
diagrams
were still new and exciting, not the tired cliche they have since become;
I still remember a bunch of us
working
out the geometry of anticipated shocks on a lunchroom table. For those
who were interested in
international
macroeconomics -- and the arrival of Rudi Dornbusch at MIT in 1975 meant
that many students were
--
there was the additional excitement of trying to figure out the new world
of floating exchange rates, at a time
when
the question seemed to be who would win the glory of having the winning
theory. (Again, the empirical
debacle
still lay in the future).
Finally,
at MIT I got my first sense of the wider role an economist can play in
the world. When he arrived at
MIT,
Rudi Dornbusch was an economist's economist, known for the didactic clarity
of his papers. As I watched,
he
was transformed into a policy guru, his advice sought by governments and
bankers around the world. I don't
know
whether the possibility for that kind of enlargment of role was truly new,
but it was new to me.
In
the summer of 1976 I got a first taste of the policy world myself, as part
of a small group of MIT students sent
to
work for the central bank of Portugal for three months. At the time Portugal
was in considerable chaos, in the
aftermath
of a revolution and an attempted coup; much of the challenge was simply
to figure out what was going
on.
What I learned from that experience was the power of very simple economic
ideas and simultaneously the
uselessness
of theories that cannot be given operational content. In particular, my
experience in a country in
which
it was a major challenge even to decide whether output was rising or falling
gave me a lasting allergy to
models
that tell you that a potentially useful policy exists without giving you
any way to determine what that
policy
is.
Although
I learned an immense amount at MIT, however, I did not exactly leave trailing
clouds of glory. I was
anxious
to get out of graduate school, for no better reason than that I was still
very shy and lonely, and that I
hoped
that getting out into the real world would help me break out of my personal
shell. (For the same reason, I
turned
down Bob Solow's offer to nominate me for the Harvard Society of Fellows;
I was afraid that I would
simply
sit alone in my office for three years). As a result, I rushed out with
a hastily written thesis, which didn't
even
include the one really good paper I had written (more on that below). Luckily
Yale offered me a job
nonetheless.
But it was not until the middle of my first year of teaching that I found
my feet as an economist.
2. Finding a vision
I wrote
the first paper I think of as characteristic when I was still in graduate
school. "A model of balance of
payments
crises" emerged while I was spending two months as an intern at the Federal
Reserve, where I realized
that
the stories Steve Salant was telling about speculative attacks on commodity
stockpiles could be applied to
currency
crises as well. Both my craftsmanship and my self-confidence were still,
however, a bit weak. The
model
contained unnecessary complications, and the writing was somewhat unclear.
Perhaps as a result, Rudi
Dornbusch,
by now my thesis adviser, didn't get the point of the first draft (neither
did the referees when I finally
submitted
it); and instead of standing up to his doubts, I simply buried the paper
until Rudi suggested I look at it
again
a year later.
I now
think that I was lucky that I put speculative attacks on hold, since I
might easily have ended up devoting
my
next few years to rational-expectations models of international finance.
Instead, I spent my first semester of
teaching
at something of a loss, and then found something much bigger: a vision
that continues to guide my
research
more than 15 years later. The vision was, of course, of the importance
of increasing returns and
imperfect
competition in trade.
I had
learned about monopolistic competition from a short course given by Bob
Solow in 1976, and I guess the
idea
of applying the new models to trade had been percolating in my mind ever
since. I have, however, a typical
pattern
in my work: I will have a foggy idea that I play with occasionally, sometimes
for years; then some event
will
suddenly cause the fog to lift, revealing an almost fully developed model.
In this case, in January 1978 I paid
a
visit to Rudi Dornbusch to talk about my work, and prepared a list of possible
ideas, including as an
afterthought
the idea of a monopolistically competitive trade model. When he flagged
the idea as interesting, I
went
home to work on it the next day -- and knew within a few hours that I had
the key to my whole career in
hand.
I distinctly remember staying up all night in excitement, feeling that
I had just seen a vision on the road to
Damascus.
Of
course it took a while to convince anyone else of the truth of that vision.
In fact the next year and a half was
deeply
frustrating: rejections by journals, lack of interest by most of my senior
colleagues (though much support
from
Carlos Diaz-Alejandro), and a decision by the Yale department not to give
me a research fellowship. I
persevered,
however, and in the spring of 1979 another patch of fog lifted, and I saw
my way clear to integrate
monopolistic
competition and comparative advantage. (I can again describe the moment
of revelation very
precisely:
the analytical trick that made the model possible came to me at Boston's
Logan Airport, where I was
waiting
for a flight to Minneapolis).
I presented
the new paper at the National Bureau of Economic Research Summer Institute
that July -- an ideal
locale,
because it guaranteed exposure to an influential group of international
economists. I still think, with all of
the
things that I have done since, that the hour and a half in which I presented
that paper was the best 90 minutes
of
my life. There's a corny scene in the movie Coal Miner's Daughter, in which
the young Loretta Lynn performs
for
the first time in a noisy bar, and little by little everyone gets quiet
and starts to listen to her singing. Well,
that's
what it felt like: I had, all at once, made it.
Made
it to what? In the modern academic world there tends, in any given field
-- whether it is international
finance,
Jane Austen studies, or some branch of endocrinology -- to be a "circuit",
the people who get invited to
speak
at academic conferences, who form a sort of de facto nomenklatura. I used
to refer to the circuit in
international
economics as the "floating crap game". It's hard to get onto the circuit
-- it takes at least two really
good
papers, one to get noticed and a second to show that the first wasn't a
fluke -- but once you are in, the
constant
round of conferences and invited papers makes it easy to stay in. By the
summer of 1980, with five or so
really
good papers either published or in the pipeline, I was pretty much guaranteed
a lifetime place.
It
seems to me that in the next couple of years, assured of a solid place
in the academic world, I actually did
slack
off a bit, although I continued to work on the economics of trade and imperfect
competition, and wrote some
papers
that I can still read without embarassment. What I mostly remember from
that time, however, is going to
conferences.
These were not lavish affairs: we are talking about flying economy class,
taking the bus in from the
airport,
and staying on the sixth floor of a hotel with no elevator or in a conference
center with bathrooms down
the
hall. Nonetheless, people were now paying my way to travel to England,
France, Italy, Germany, Spain,
Finland,
Sweden, Switzerland, Israel, Mexico. I was finally having the exotic experiences
that I had missed when
younger
-- except, of course, that I kept meeting the same people wherever I went!
I have
never left the academic circuit, and I never will. I have been a bit cynical
about how that circuit works,
but
its members constitute a true, and wonderfully unpretentious, elite. A
few weeks before writing this piece I
attended
an international trade conference held in a classroom in Milan. The room
was shabby, with seats so
uncomfortable
that several older participants ended up with back problems. The hotel
was decent but austere. Yet
I
can assure you that there was more real insight in the discussion than
you will find in a dozen G7 summits. I
hope
that I never forget that it is young economists in blue jeans, not famous
officials in pinstripes, who really
have
interesting things to say. And yet I was not satisfied. No doubt this had
a lot to do with personal issues of
the
kind that I won't discuss here, but after three years of academic conferences
I was jaded and a little bored. I
was
ready to jump at the opportunity to do something different, if not in the
end better.
3. Washington
In
August of 1982 I flew home from a conference in Sweden to find a message
to call Martin Feldstein. Two
weeks
later I had arranged for a leave from MIT and was on my way to Washington,
to be the chief staffer for
international
economics at the Council of Economic Advisers.
It
was, in a way, strange for me to be part of the Reagan Administration.
I was then and still am an unabashed
defender
of the welfare state, which I regard as the most decent social arrangement
yet devised. I am also unable
to
pretend to respect "policy entrepreneurs", the intellectually dishonest
self-proclaimed experts who tell
politicians
what they want to hear. The Reagan Administration was, of course, full
of people who hated the
welfare
state and had very little interest in the truth. But the summer of 1982
was a moment of near-panic among
the
Reaganauts, as the recession and the debt crisis seemed to threaten catastrophe.
They not only hired
Feldstein,
they gave him the freedom to bring in a politically incorrect team of whiz-kids
(which included Larry
Summers
and Greg Mankiw) in the hope that he could turn things around. By 1983,
with a recovery well under
way,
the political types were back in charge and Feldstein was ostracized for
worrying publically about the
budget
deficit; but that came later.
Washington
was first thrilling, then disillusioning. It is the capital of the world,
and for a young person it is
wonderful
to think that you can really have an effect on decisions of global importance.
I can still recite from
memory
the long list of prohibitions on the front page of each classified document
("Secret/No foreign
nationals/No
contractors/Proprietary information/Origin controlled"). Some people get
addicted to that thrill, and
will
do anything to stay near the center.
After
a little while, however, I began to notice how policy decisions are really
made. The fact is that most senior
officials
have no idea what they are talking about: discussion at high-level meetings
is startlingly primitive. (For
example,
the distinction between nominal and real interest rates tends to be regarded
as a complex and useless
bit
of academic nitpicking). Furthermore, many powerful people prefer to take
advice from those who make them
feel
comfortable rather than from those who will force them to think hard. That
is, those who really manage to
influence
policy are usually the best courtiers, not the best analysts. I like to
think that I am a good analyst, but I
am
certainly a very bad courtier. And so I was not tempted to stay on in Washington.
I did,
however, discover a new talent: that of writing serious economics in seemingly
plain English. I got to
practice
that talent in writing classified memos, and proved good enough at it that
I ended up writing most of the
1983
Economic Report of the President. Ever since, I have used non-technical
writing about economics as the
basis
for a sort of parallel career, one that keeps me on the fringes of the
policy world though rarely at its
center.
I made a good start on that parallel career just after leaving Washington,
by writing a paper for a major
conference
on industrial policy. That paper was deeply critical of some of the industrial
policy proposals that
were
circulating at that time, and was critical in particular of what I considered
the foolish proposals of a policy
entrepreneur
by the name of Robert Reich. In so doing I had planted a time bomb which
only went off nine years
later.
4. Consolidation and crisis
I spent
one year in Washington, and was then faced with the problem of reintegrating
myself into academic life --
not
an easy task. Often a period of work in policy seems to destroy the capacity
to do academic research. It's not
just
that writing papers lacks the thrill of directly influencing events. It's
also that once you've seen the primitive
nature
of real policy discussion, you start to wonder whether third-order conditions
or likelihood-ratio tests can
really
matter. But I was lucky, because a colleague took me in hand.
During
the academic year 1983-4 Elhanan Helpman of Tel-Aviv University was visiting
at MIT, and he persuaded
me
to work with him on a magnum opus synthesizing the work on the "new trade
theory", the merger of industrial
organization
and trade that he and I had helped pioneer. What followed was a ten-month
period of total
immersion,
out of which emerged Market Structure and Foreign Trade, which served all
the purposes Elhanan had
in
mind: not only did it synthesize the field, but by offering a single, comprehensive
reference it was a great
advertising
device. That is, from that point on, if anyone asked "What's this new trade
theory about?", he could
simply
be told to read our book. That was good for the new trade theory, and not
incidentally good for our own
careers.
After
this huge effort, I fell into something of a work slump. In fact, from
my point of view I went into a
three-year
professional crisis. From the outside this may not have been obvious. After
all, I was by now a tenured
professor
at the world's leading economics department, and was still a very active
member of the conference
circuit.
I even wrote several pretty good papers during that time. Yet from the
inside, I felt that I had lost my
sense
of what I was supposed to be doing; the good papers felt like isolated
stunts, not like part of an ongoing
quest.
To
be honest, I also felt underappreciated. At one level, this was petty:
I had a very pleasant job that paid quite
well
and received lots of invitations to conferences around the world. Compared
with 99.9 percent of humanity, I
had
nothing to complain about. But of course that isn't the way the human animal
is constructed. My emotional
reference
group consisted of the most successful economists of my generation, and
I was not generally counted
among
their number.
I hit
an emotional low point in the spring and summer of 1987. I was turned down
for several grants, substantially
complicating
my plans to take an academic leave the next year; and I didn't seem to
have any real momentum
going
on in my research. I went to conferences, but it seemed like going through
the motions. And then, somehow,
it
all fell into place again.
5. Getting back on track
In
the second half of 1987 I suddenly experienced an explosion of research
productivity. I'm not quite sure why,
but
I can think of several reasons.
One
was that I took a year's leave from MIT and spent it sitting at the National
Bureau of Economic Research.
The
NBER is a cramped environment, with several dozen smart young economists
crammed close together. It isn't
very
comfortable, but at any given time there is nearly always an interesting
conversation about economics going
on
in the coffee room; I don't know anyplace else as stimulating.
Another
reason was that I had, without quite knowing it, been accumulating material.
Over the previous two
years,
lacking fundamental research ideas (and needing money), I had gone to many
policy-oriented conferences:
conferences
that would provide an honorarium for a sensible but not necessarily innovative
paper on the dollar, on
developing
country debt, on the trade deficit, and so on. I was pretty good at this,
because of the skill I had
developed
at writing serious economics in non-technical language. Not many theorists
are able or willing to
participate
in this somewhat different conference circuit, so I was in the fairly unique
position of being a clever
model-builder
who had a good sense of what the trendy international economic issues of
the day were, of what
was
on the minds of people who cared about policy.
Finally,
it may sound silly, but I think that the advent of improved software for
personal computers, and
especially
the availability of laptop machines that could come with me on my international
travels, encouraged
me
to write technical papers. I am an extremely fast but disorganized and
impatient worker; a technology that
lets
me produce a paper -- equations, simulations, and all -- in a hotel room
somewhere over a weekend perfectly
fits
my style.
Anyway,
whatever the reason, in 1987 and 1988 I began writing a torrent of papers.
I actually don't know how
many
-- there were about eight serious theory papers that remain relevant, and
probably another fifteen topical
conference
papers, not to mention two co-authored books. (By the way, the times and
ways in which ideas float up
remained
fairly strange. My basic model of exchange rate target zones, arguably
my most successful single paper,
came
to me during a flight from Tokyo to London).
The
papers I wrote during that spurt were different from those I had written
during my first few years after
graduate
school. My earlier work had tended to draw its motivation entirely from
the logic of economic research,
addressing
enduring questions like "why is there international trade?" Now I found
myself writing papers that
took
a current policy concern -- Third World debt reduction, the working of
the EMS, the apparent trend toward
trading
blocs -- as a starting point. From there I would develop a small, elegant
model that would in effect
provide
a language for discussing the issue. Some of the issues I worked on have
faded into obscurity; but it turns
out
that the models tend to live on.
The
work I did in 1987 and 1988 ended my own self-doubts about research. And
I would be dishonest if I didn't
admit
that there was also a gratifying change in my professional standing. The
conference invitations got fancier
--
although, as I suspected, it turned out that the lavishness of a conference
and its intellectual quality are almost
perfectly
negatively correlated. More important, there seemed to be a growing appreciation
outside of
international
trade of what the new trade theory had achieved. This appreciation was
eventually reflected in some
serious
academic gongs: Elhanan Helpman received the Israel Prize, an all-academic
honor that is at least as
hard
to get as a Nobel Prize, and I got the American Economic Association's
John Bates Clark Medal. The
important
point is that in 1987 and 1988 I had, once again, made it past a sort of
barrier. And I was again not
satisfied:
I wanted to try something new.
6. A broader audience
In
the fall of 1988 Michael Barker, a former Congressional aide now working
for The Washington Post,
approached
me about a book project. He wanted me to write a primer on the US economy
for a new series of
"briefing
books" the Post was planning to issue. Rather casually I agreed, and after
much procrastination I spent
most
of a summer on Martha's Vineyard pounding out The Age of Diminished Expectations.
It turned out that I
wrote
a different sort of book than either Michael or I had expected. It was,
indeed, a primer on the US economy;
but
it was also a kind of stealth textbook on economic theory, turning the
real economic problems of the United
States
into a series of parables that illustrated economic principles, with sophisticated
models hidden under the
seemingly
plain prose. It wasn't to everyone's taste, but it quickly became a sort
of cult book, with a devoted
following.
Diminished
Expectations never became a true best-seller. I like to blame the marketing
and distribution, over
which
I never had any control. But the book did reach a much larger audience
than anything else I had written,
and
did a lot to open new doors to me. Journalists read Diminished Expectations
and then called me for stories;
businessmen
read it and asked me to speak at conferences. And of course each interview
in the press or business
speech
led to further calls.
This
was not all to the good. The pace of my life changed; I had always been
busy, but now I found myself in
constant
and unhappy overdrive. I signed with an agency to negotiate speaking deals,
not for the business they
could
bring but for their ability to demand high fees and thus ration my time.
(I got pretty good at the speaking,
however,
and the fees started to get high enough to tempt me into doing too much
of it). I found that an hour or
two
of each day was spent on the phone with reporters. Luckily for my sanity
and future productivity, however, I
did
not break through into a role as TV personality. If I had, I do not know
if I could have found the
self-discipline
to continue with research.
My
role as a public person soared during the 1992 Presidential campaign, then
took a nosedive soon afterwards.
What
propelled my visibility upwards was my role in a bitter public dispute
over income distribution. It is a fact
that
income inequality in the US soared during the Reagan years, but it is a
fact that conservatives are reluctant
to
admit. I had included a chapter on inequality in Diminished Expectations
-- over the objections, by the way, of
my
editors, who didn't think it was important. I came back to the issue in
some Congressional testimony early in
1992.
In particular, I thought up a useful way to dramatize the extent of the
inequality: some 70 percent of the
increase
in average family income from 1977 to 1989 had gone to the top one percent
of families. This number
made
a good sound bite, and was eagerly seized upon by the Clinton campaign.
The
next few months were a strange time, as I, with a little help from friends
in the press, waged what amounted
to
a propaganda war with the editor of the Wall Street Journal. I think I
won that war -- in the end, the point was
that
inequality had indeed increased sharply, and efforts to deny that eventually
looked silly. But it meant that for
much
of that year I was playing a far more public role than ever before. Inevitably
this brought me into some
contact
with the Clinton campaign. I wrote an op-ed piece endorsing their economic
plan, and met the candidate
once.
In the newspapers, of course, I was touted as a likely chairman of the
Council of Economic Advisers.
In
fact, however, key advisers to Clinton knew me from way back, and the memories
were not friendly.
Immediately
after the election, Robert Reich -- the same policy entrepreneur I had
attacked in 1983 -- was named
head
of the economic transition team. And to my dismay, it quickly became clear
not only that I would be
excluded
from influence, which didn't bother me too much, but that the Clinton Administration
was going to
systematically
prefer policy entrepreneurs to real experts. In particular, it became apparent
that the dominant
ideology
of the new administration would be what I call "pop internationalism",
a foolish analogy between
international
trade and corporate competition. And because no first-rate economists would
or could accept this
doctrine,
the key positions were filled by second-rate people.
I did
not take this development gracefully. I said what I thought, in letters
and interviews. And of course the
press
-- as always deferring to a new President, and impressed by his articulateness
-- ridiculed my complaints,
ascribing
them to sour grapes over not having received an appointment myself. A few
months later everyone was
complaining
about the quality of the new Administration's personnel, but there is no
memory in these matters; I
was
more or less disgraced, and my public profile was and still is much lower
than at its peak.
This
story may not be over. I have another plain-English book in the works,
and do not plan to stay out of public
controversies
forever. But I do not expect or want to have the kind of fever-pitch political
involvement I had in
1992
again. I was able to face the unpleasantness of how my venture into politics
turned out with considerable
equanimity,
for two reasons. One was that my personal life had taken a turn for the
better. The other was that I
had
once again gotten hold of a grand research project that I found inspiring
and absorbing.
7. Back to the vision
There
is a rhythm in my professional interests. When I have been concentrating
on academic research for several
years,
I tend to get a bit bored and want to get involved in policy; when I have
done policy for a while, I start to
have
the itch to do real research again. (I get tired of policy much more quickly
than I get tired of research).
True
to this rhythm, soon after I finished Diminished Expectations I was anxious
to do some real thinking again. I
found
the clue to a new project when Michael Porter, the business strategist,
sent me a manuscript of his
forthcoming
book The Competitive Advantage of Nations. It's a mammoth book, and I never
did read it all, but I
was
very taken with his emphasis on the role of regional industrial clusters
in international competition. Soon I
started
thinking about trying to develop models of economic geography. I started
with complicated ideas, then
gradually
boiled them down. I distinctly recall filling many sheets of scrap paper
during a sleepless night at the
faculty
club at the University of British Columbia, and calculating many numerical
examples in a hotel room in
Hawaii.
After a few months I had a basic model ready to submit for publication;
by the fall of 1990 I was ready
to
give a set of lectures on the subject, Geography and Trade, which has become
another cult classic.
Economic
geography has turned out to be a richer research vein than the subjects
I mined in the late 1980s; I
have
written six serious papers on the subject already, and do not feel that
I am close to exhausting its potential.
I
have also engaged in a systematic process of proselytizing on its behalf;
my intention is to establish economic
geography
as a branch of economics that is taken as seriously as international trade,
and I believe that I will
succeed
in that plan.
Coming
up with a good idea, with an insight into the way the world works that
is really new and that you really
believe
in, is a deeply satisfying experience. The only thing that is even more
satisfying is when one idea leads
on
to another, when you find yourself making a whole series of related discoveries.
When that happens, never
mind
if you are a shy and mild-mannered professor: you feel like some archetypal
hero on a mythic quest. I count
myself
very lucky to have had that feeling even once, during the development of
the new trade theory. It is little
short
of a miracle that I have been able to experience it a second time, as the
new economic geography has taken
shape.
What
makes it even more satisfying is the relationship between the two quests.
Economic geography, like the new
trade
theory, is largely about increasing returns and multiple equilibria. The
technical tricks needed to make the
models
tractable are often the same. There is a difference in emphasis -- the
trade models were largely focussed
on
internal economies of scale, while geography is largely about external
economies -- and in policy relevance.
Nonetheless,
it is clear that the two lines of research are in some sense part of a
larger project. So I have the
satisfaction
of being able to feel that I have done more than written two dozen or so
clever papers: I have been
engaged
in some kind of cumulative enterprise. In the remainder of this paper I
will try to explain what I think
the
nature of that enterprise has been -- that is, to justify myself as an
economist.
8. What have I been up to?
Anyone
who does creative work must, of necessity, be something of a sleepwalker,
because future creative work
is
by its nature unpredictable. You can't know what you're going to do over
the next few years, because if you did
you
would in effect already have done it. It's only when you look back that
you can see the shape, grasp the
pattern.
The pattern in my own work has two main aspects. One is its substance,
the core set of ideas that have
informed
many of the papers worth remembering. The other is its style -- a distinctive
way of approaching
problems
that is closely linked to the substance.
Substance
As
the narrative above makes clear, I have worked and written on a lot of
topics. It is, however, the idea of
increasing
returns that has been the most important theme in my work. And it is my
work in helping to clarify the
role
that increasing returns plays in economics that is the main excuse I have
for my existence. The idea of
increasing
returns is, of course, a very old one, going back at least to Adam Smith.
Nonetheless, until the 1980s
economics
was heavily dominated by what we may call the Ricardian Simplification:
the assumption of constant
returns
and perfect competition.
There
is no mystery or shame involved in that domination: strategic simplification
is the essence of all
understanding
except in the most fundamental physics. The constant returns-competitive
model offers a
remarkable
if somewhat incomplete view of how the world works; in terms of economic
policy, 95 percent of the
time
it would be a blessing if politicians could understand what's right about
the constant returns model, not
what's
wrong with it. Nonetheless, the world isn't really characterized by constant
returns, and it was essential to
go
beyond the Ricardian Simplification, if only to be able to say to the policymakers
that we had explored that
terrain
and found little of use.
If
one admits increasing returns into one's economic model, two other consequences
follow. First, increasing
returns
are intimately bound up with the possibility of multiple equilibria. There
can be multiple equilibria in
constant-returns
models, too, but they are rarely either plausible or interesting. By contrast,
it is very easy to be
persuaded
of both the relevance and importance of multiple equilibria due to increasing
returns. What technology
will
be chosen for high-definition television? Which city will be Europe's financial
center? These are real and
interesting
questions. Second, once there are interesting multiple equilibria, you
need a story about how the
economy
picks one. The natural stories involve dynamics -- the cumulation of initial
advantages that may be
accidents
of history.
Speaking
loosely, then, traditional economic analysis has -- for very good reasons
-- focussed largely on static
models
in which equilibrium is uniquely determined by tastes, technology and factor
endowments. An economic
analysis
that takes increasing returns seriously will normally involve dynamic models
in which the choice of
equilibrium
also reflects history.
All
of this is fairly obvious, and indeed the history of thought in economics
is littered with manifestos on the
need
to take into account increasing returns, multiple equilibria, dynamics,
and the role of history. Nicholas
Kaldor,
for example, delivered strident attacks on constant-returns economics in
the late 1960s; Thomas Schelling
offered
elegant little parables about dynamics and multiple equilibria in a series
of papers during the 1970s.
Nonetheless,
it wasn't until the 1980s that increasing returns really got into the mainstream
of economics. I
wasn't
the only one in the movement: Paul Romer, in particular, wrote several
papers I wish I had written (I can
think
of no higher praise!) applying increasing returns to economic growth. But
I think it's fair to say that my
work
first on trade and then on geography did as much as anyone's to really
put increasing returns on the
professional
map.
In
the new trade theory, the basic point was that increasing returns are a
motive for specialization and trade over
and
above conventional comparative advantage, and can indeed cause trade even
where comparative advantage is
of
negligible importance -- for example, among industrial countries with similar
resources and technology. The
pattern
of specialization and trade caused by increasing returns is, however, somewhat
arbitrary; one must appeal
to
historical accident to explain who produces what. This seems pretty obvious,
yet until the new trade theorists
got
going it was not part of mainstream thinking. It is a fact of life that
trained economists find it very difficult
to
see the obvious unless it has been encapsulated in a clear formal model.
(That's not an attack on the enterprise
of
modeling: those who believe that by engaging in fuzzy thinking they can
widen their horizons almost always
see
even less). The few existing models of trade under increasing returns were
somehow too awkward to be
persuasive.
My own view is that the problem was largely one of style, something I'll
turn to shortly, and that my
big
contribution was to break through an intellectual style barrier. Whatever
the reason, before 1980 the potential
role
of increasing returns in international trade was virtually ignored by economists;
by 1987 or so it had become
part
of the standard story. That's a pretty big intellectual shift, and I think
it's fair to claim that Elhanan Helpman
and
I deserve most of the credit.
In
the area of economic geography, the basic point is that the economic landscape
is covered with examples of
agglomeration
-- geographical concentrations of population and activity in general, like
Los Angeles,
concentration
of particular types of business like Silicon Valley. These agglomerations
are rarely explainable by
special
inherent resources of the site; they are, rather, examples of increasing
returns at work. And the role of
history
in their formation is obvious: there has been no important commercial traffic
on the Erie Canal since
1850,
yet the head start that canal gave to New York City has allowed New York
to remain the largest US city to
this
day. Again, all of this is obvious. And yet the apparent difficulty in
modeling the increasing-returns nature of
agglomeration
had excluded this obvious story from the economic mainstream. Even today,
the new economic
principles
textbook by Joseph Stiglitz contains exactly one reference to cities in
its 1200 pages -- a brief
discussion
of rural-urban migration in the Third World! I'm pretty sure this will
change.
The
geography models I have been writing since 1990 have inspired a growing
number of followers, including a
growing
body of empirical work. It's a reasonable prediction that ten years from
now the new economic geography
will
be as firmly established as the new trade theory. If so, I will have succeeded
in bringing a quite large chunk
of
increasing-returns-based analysis into the heart of mainstream economics.
That, I think, is my main
achievement.
What has made it possible, however, is not so much special insight -- both
in trade and in geography
it
is possible to point to many people who have expressed similar ideas --
as style. Indeed, I regard the
intellectual
style I have developed as central to the whole enterprise.
Style
Robert
Solow used to tell his students that there were two kinds of theorists:
those who like to generalize, and
those
who like to look for illuminating special cases. I fall very strongly into
the latter camp. Indeed, I have
elevated
the creation of special cases into a sort of personal art form. In constant-returns
models, it is often
possible
once you have made the big untrue assumptions up front to derive results
of considerable generality. For
example,
the Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson model does not depend on any assumptions
about the degree of
substitutability
between capital and labor. You may want to look at, say, a Leontief or
a Cobb-Douglas technology
as
an interesting example, but you don't have to. In increasing-returns models,
by contrast, there are very few
general
results. Even with two goods, two countries, and one factor of production
one easily bogs down in a
complex
taxonomy. So what do you do?
My
answer has been to rely heavily on those suggestive special cases. The
process works like this: start with an
informal
verbal story, often one drawn from casual empiricism or from non-mainstream
economic literature. Then
try
to build the simplest possible model that will illustrate that story. In
the course of the model-building the
story
tends to change along with your intuition, but at the end of the process
you have a simple model that is a
very
special case, but that makes a lot of intuitive sense and effectively gives
you a language to discuss things
that
previously were off limits. The intuition can then also serve as the basis
for empirical work, although to be
honest
I have never been a very persistent econometrician.
How
do you find special cases that work, that allow you to go where no modeler
has gone before? Any way you
can.
At various times I have assumed particular functional forms; symmetry;
two states of nature where you
might
expect to find a continuum, or a continuum of goods where the traditional
models have two; and in some
cases
relied on numerical examples where pencil and paper fail. It's a sort of
blitzkrieg approach to theory:
instead
of trying to advance on a broad front, one tries to get as far as possible
along a narrow corridor of
advance,
taking advantage of any weak points you can find.
This
style is not, of course, original. For classic examples, consider some
of the early work on growth and
technical
change, say Arrow's model of learning by doing or Solow's vintage capital
model. In those papers all of
the
elements of the style are there: an intuitive story based on casual empiricism,
embodied in a model that relies
crucially
on special functional forms to be tractable, yet which seems to offer important
further insights. What I
did
was to apply the method repeatedly in the service of a cause I believed
in, that of making economic theory
safe
for increasing returns.
The
style works for other things as well, however. The policy-inspired models
I did in the late 1980s -- on
sovereign
debt, target zones, trading blocs, exchange rates -- followed the same
approach. In these papers policy
relevance
and analytical elegance seemed to me, and to a fair number of other people,
to be surprisingly natural
allies:
it turns out that a crisp, minimalist model may be just what is needed
to clear out some of the nonsense in
a
policy discussion and get down to the real issues.
One
might also speculate that my relative success at writing economics in plain
English has something to do with
modeling
style. After all, once you have accepted that models are metaphors rather
than ultimate truth, and have
schooled
yourself to make the metaphors as simple as possible, it may be easier
to find non-mathematical
metaphors
as well. Or to put it a different way: once you have stripped an idea down
to its essence, it is often
surprisingly
possible to express that essence without any visible display of technique.
In summary, then, whatever
contribution
I may have made to economics has involved both substance -- the integration
of increasing returns
into
economics -- and style -- radical simplification as a modeling strategy.
The style is essential to the
substance
but also has a life of its own, and has allowed me to make productive raids
into a number of areas
other
than increasing returns.
9. The point of it all
Perhaps
in the end the question one should ask of any scholar is what purpose he
feels his work serves. I could
claim
great nobility of character and tell you that I work for the good of humanity.
Or I could try to shock you
and
tell you that all I care about are the financial and professional rewards.
Neither would be entirely false. I
am,
indeed, a bit of a romantic who believes, rather in the face of the evidence,
that good ideas eventually
prevail
and make everyone's life better. I am also not an ascetic: I will not sneer
at a nice honorarium or a free
trip
to a pleasant location.
But
the honest truth is that what drives me as an economist is that economics
is fun. I think I understand why so
many
people think that economics is a boring subject, but they are wrong. On
the contrary, there is hardly
anything
I know that is as exciting as finding that the great events that move history,
the forces that determine
the
destiny of empires and the fate of kings, can sometimes be explained, predicted,
or even controlled by a few
symbols
on a printed page. We all want power, we all want success, but the ultimate
reward is the simple joy of
understanding.